Ever found yourself tapping your foot at the till of your favourite clothing store or doing something more violent in that funky denim studio? Can you blame your compulsion to purchase that new bag solely on a mild personality disorder or should the background beat-of-the-street shoulder some of the blame? Facts are that atmospheric music is played by retailers and not just to soften the ring of the register but also because it is enjoyable and encourages sales. But how much do they pay and is it proportionate?
Late last year the Supreme Court of Appeal (the SCA - RSA’s highest
commercial court) grappled with a rare case involving music royalties. The
case, originally brought by a group of prominent retailers against the South African Performance Rights Association (SAMPRA) for charging excess rates for
the licensing of background music that they played in their stores, is interesting
because it is one of the very few cases on the determination of a reasonable royalty
in South Africa. In this case, the court determined royalties based on
international norms but not before dealing with a number of arguments related
to the construction of the legislation, onus, competition law and property
rights. The full case can be found here.
http://www.sampra.org.za/ |
Background
The retailer's obligation to pay a royalty is contained in s
9(A)(1)(a) of the Copyright Act 98 of 1978 (the Act). This section provides
that in the absence of an agreement to the contrary no person may broadcast a
sound recording without payment of a royalty to SAMPRA which is an accredited
collecting society. This royalty is payable according to a tariff which is
determined by agreement between the user and the performer and in the absence
of an agreement, the determination may be referred to the Copyright Tribunal set
up under the Act.
As one might expect there was a failure to reach an
agreement and the matter was referred to the tribunal which then issued a
ruling. No unsurprisingly too, after much debate this ruling found that a reasonable
tariff lay somewhere between what the retailers and SAMPRA each thought was
reasonable, with a cost order in favour of the retailers. SAMPRA appealed and
there was no cross appeal from the retailers. Apparently cross though, the retailers opposed the appeal.
Basis of appeal
This can be summarised as follows:
- There was a failure of the tribunal to consider principles of competition law in determining the royalty;
- The tribunal’s authority to make a ruling only triggered once the retailers had established that the tariff was unreasonable which they had not done. This was effectively an argument based on onus and jurisdiction of the tribunal which SAMPRA thought had been misconstrued; and
- That the retailers were obliged to disclose the Rand value derived from the use of the sound recordings, which they had not done, in determining the reasonableness of the tariff
On the question as to whether completion law principles were
applied, the court gave short shrift to the argument and held that these were
entirely new submissions and that it would be unfair to allow this now. Afro
Leo suggests that procedurally this was the right approach and that although the
competition arguments would have been very interesting to understand it appears somewhat desperate of SAMPRA. In any event, this Leo
wonders whether, when determining reasonableness, competition elements are
naturally considered without formal recourse to of this silo of law/economics?
The construction of the Act was much debated and considered
by the SCA. The Act is ambiguous in its construction and described (with
reference to Dean’s Handbook of South African Copyright Law) as a “rather tortuous
statutory scheme in terms in terms of which the tribunal derives its power”. Afro Leo agrees. For those interested in the doing some mind gym have a look at paras 12-30 of
the judgment. Essentially, the court held that all that is required of
retailers or claimant is to place evidence before the tribunal that the claim
is well founded (there is no formal onus of proof) and “At the end of the day
for the claimant to succeed the tribunal is required to be satisfied, on all
the evidence placed before it [presumably including that of the respondent],
that the claim is well founded.” This seems sensible.
Necessity of showing rand value
The question of whether the retailers should have lead evidence of
the rand value they derived from use of the sound recording was considered; the
argument essentially being that under the construction of S33(5)(b) of the Act,
only once it had been established that this value was disproportionately lower than
the proposed tariff could it be unreasonable, and that it would need to cause
economic harm to the retailer. In addition, the recordings needed to sustain
their business and no available alternative would serve the retailers economic
interests (see paras 31- 37) . And you thought Everest was a challenge!
After hearing various experts on whether this information
was available, how such a study would be conducted, what its probative value
would be and sensitivities over confidentiality [the arguments are
interesting], the court held that such evidence would be “prohibitively expensive
and impractical as it would take too long to complete. In addition, it cannot
be said that any conclusion reached could apply to all retailers” and therefore
“not necessary”.
Afro Leo thinks that this is the correct ruling and wonders whether the court would take such a pragmatic approach to the evidence required to prove economic harm in trade mark dilution cases. Another reason why it seems correct is that in the Copyright Act, there exists a concept of a reasonable royalty in lieu of showing damages; implicitly recognising the difficulty of showing actual damage.
Afro Leo thinks that this is the correct ruling and wonders whether the court would take such a pragmatic approach to the evidence required to prove economic harm in trade mark dilution cases. Another reason why it seems correct is that in the Copyright Act, there exists a concept of a reasonable royalty in lieu of showing damages; implicitly recognising the difficulty of showing actual damage.
The two proffered by resident Profs were the “market-based
solution” and by benchmarking with tariffs used in other jurisdictions.
The market based approach essentially meant that, in the absence
of an agreement, the market should be left to naturally determine the tariff. This
approach was given short thrift by the court (just a single paragraph) after
the Prof conceded that he was not aware of the legal framework which directed the tribunal to determine the
tariff. The court was perhaps too hasty
here in its reasoning for it is still possible for the tribunal to determine
the tariff, and then use a market based approach in its determination.